[Mb-civic] A washingtonpost.com article from: swiggard@comcast.net

swiggard at comcast.net swiggard at comcast.net
Mon Apr 25 04:00:10 PDT 2005


You have been sent this message from swiggard at comcast.net as a courtesy of washingtonpost.com 
 
 The Democracy Trap
 
 By Sebastian Mallaby
 
  It's easy to want democracy for the Middle East. But what sort of democracy? Should American foreign policy focus on promoting elections, or on checks and balances? Is the crucial question how power is achieved? Or is it how power is exercised?
 
 Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler, two economists at Oxford University, address these questions in a new paper on oil-rich democracies. Their answer, rooted in statistical analysis of oil states' performance since 1970 under various types of political systems, is that the tendency to focus on elections is correct in most societies but misguided in oil states. In a country such as Iraq, the United States and its allies should care at least as much about the quality of Iraq's judiciary and media as about the quality of its voting.
 
 Collier and Hoeffler are actually nicer about elections than most development economists are. Until the 1990s the research consensus held that voting was bad for economic growth, a finding that fitted with the idea that dictators are better at imposing necessary austerity. In the past decade or so, researchers have generally found that elections are more or less growth-neutral. But by taking countries with natural resources out of the sample, Collier and Hoeffler show that ordinary, resource-poor nations grow faster if they have elections.
 
 In oil states, however, the opposite holds true--at least if elections are held in the absence of checks and balances. In countries where natural-resource profits come to a fifth of GDP, the switch from autocracy to electoral competition lowers the annual growth rate by a hefty 2.1 percentage points. Unless there are checks and balances, elections cause oil-rich countries to invest less than they should -- and to invest badly. As a result they fail to create the public infrastructure that makes growth possible.
 
 Why might elections promote growth in most countries but cause underinvestment in oil states? In ordinary countries, where the state has limited cash at its disposal, the most efficient way to attract votes is to provide public goods: low inflation, rule of law, infrastructure that's carefully chosen to benefit the whole society. So elections promote pro-growth policies. In petro-states, by contrast, the simplest way to attract votes is to buy them. Politicians can do that by subsidizing food or handing out government jobs in exchange for loyalty, bribes th  at promote consumption at the expense of investment. Or they can blow money on projects whose real purpose is to generate kickbacks, so what little investment there is tends to be junky.
 
 A good example is Nigeria, which has yo-yoed between military dictatorship and corrupt democracy. In 1978 a new elected government came to power and canceled a $120 million dam contract that had been awarded by the outgoing military dictatorship. A new contract was awarded, but this time it was so padded with kickbacks that it cost an astonishing $600 million. Politicians had spent a fortune getting elected and now needed repayment.
 
 Nigeria's more recent transition to democracy, in 1999, at first seemed little better -- a fact more recently underlined by the anti-corruption drive launched by the democratic president. By the simple expedient of requiring competitive bidding for government contracts, and by checking bid prices against prices for comparable projects posted on the Internet, Nigeria has cut the cost of public-works projects by 40 percent, saving about $2 billion since 2003. Last year the minister for public service reform abolished his own department: He had examined its 25,000-strong payroll and found 5,000 "ghosts"--workers who drew salaries without ever coming to the office.
 
 So oil-rich societies need to couple elections with checks on elected authorities, as Nigeria is now attempting. This isn't true of ordinary countries; Collier and Hoeffler find that checks and balances in resource-poor countries tend to reduce growth, perhaps because they create gridlock in place of necessary public action. But in oil-rich societies a freedom of information act, an independent public prosecutor, and some separation of power over the public purse are essential to counteract incentives for corruption.
 
 This conclusion needs to register with the Bush administration. It's natural to defer to Iraqi leaders as they write their constitution this year; after all, it's their country. But the political class in any nation has few incentives to create checks on its own freedom to govern, and elections, which take place only occasionally and attract lots of healthy international attention, are easier to get right than the boring details of competitive tendering. Left to its own devices, Iraq is likely to fall into the trap that Collier and Hoeffler describe -- a constitution that focuses adequately on how power is achieved but too little on how it is exercised.
 
 mallabys at washpost.com
 
 
 
 
 Would you like to send this article to a friend? Go to 
http://www.washingtonpost.com/ac2/wp-dyn/emailafriend?contentId=AR2005042400892&sent=no&referrer=emailarticle
 
 

Visit washingtonpost.com today for the latest in:

News - http://www.washingtonpost.com/?referrer=emailarticle

Politics - http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/politics/?referrer=emailarticle

Sports - http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/sports/?referrer=emailarticle

Entertainment - http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/artsandliving/entertainmentguide/?referrer=emailarticle

Travel - http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/travel/?referrer=emailarticle

Technology - http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/technology/?referrer=emailarticle




Want the latest news in your inbox? Check out washingtonpost.com's e-mail newsletters:

http://www.washingtonpost.com/ac2/wp-dyn?node=admin/email&referrer=emailarticle

Washingtonpost.Newsweek Interactive
c/o E-mail Customer Care
1515 N. Courthouse Road
Arlington, VA 22201 

© 2004 The Washington Post Company



More information about the Mb-civic mailing list